Section 2 Symposium: Howard Marvel–An Economist’s View

Howard Marvel —  4 May 2009

marvelHoward P. Marvel is Professor of Economics in the Department of Economics and Professor of Law in the Moritz College of Law, both at The Ohio State University.

In the wake of Bork and Posner, and Baxter and the Reagan Revolution, a consensus emerged that big could be bad, but the harm that dominant firms could do needed to be demonstrated, not simply assumed in consequence of their sheer size. Moreover, the demonstration required harm to competition. The consensus held through the Clinton Administration, buoyed by the talented economists that it attracted. The Section 2 Report is controversial in drawing lines about where harm to competition begins, but it is not hard to imagine all sides of the debate agreeing with this from the report: “Competition is ill-served by insisting that firms pull their competitive punches so as to avoid the degree of marketplace success that gives them monopoly power or by demanding that winning firms, once they achieve such power, ‘lie down and play dead.’ ” (Report, p.8)

Or at least it was not difficult to limit the ground rules under which the debate would take place. But times have changed. We now worry not just about whether dominant firms abuse their positions.  Add the worry that they are too big to fail. Nobody appears concerned about GM preying upon its rivals, or even whether its new owners-you, me and the UAW-might be tempted to run the company in an anticompetitive fashion backed by Federal power. But we might have preferred to see Chevy, Cadillac, Saturn, and the rest fold asynchronously, permitting us to stand on the sidelines as the calamity proceeded slowly enough to allow each succeeding failure to be digested separately.  Who could break up the behemoths into little pieces? Calling Senator Sherman.

It’s no surprise to observe nostalgia for regulation when markets are shaky. George Stigler likened the tendency to “solve” market failures with regulation to the judge of an opera contest who, when asked to pick the best of two sopranos, awarded his prize to the second immediately upon hearing the first.  But the desire is unmistakable. George Akerlof and Robert Shiller hark back to earlier times when intervention into markets was held in high regard: “We had forgotten the hard-earned lesson of the 1930s: Capitalism can give us real prosperity, but it does so only on a playing field where the government sets the rules and acts as a referee.”

Are you pining for the NIRA? Hoping for a spectral visit from Gardiner Means? Maybe not, but an ambitious antitrust regulator will likely want to pitch in when big firms are in the regulatory crosshairs. Here’s Neelie Kroes (European Commissioner for Competition Policy): “The wider lesson for all policymakers and public authorities is that those who share common goals must work together. For example, competition authorities and central banks cannot afford to operate in their own little worlds – we must work together on issues like bank recapitalisations and restructures.”

The problem is that it is hard to pitch in for the regulatory team if your mission is restricted to protecting competition. Some financial firms may have preyed upon unsophisticated consumers, so their could be a role for the FTC’s Bureau of Consumer Protection, but it is pretty hard to make a case that the big banks cooked up the financial calamity to run investment bankers out of business. That hasn’t stopped MIT Professor Simon Johnson from suggesting that

The Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division should be called in to investigate the increasing market share of major banks (remember that Bear Stearns and Lehman are gone), the anti-competitive practices of some market leaders (there’s more than one predatory way to force your rivals into bankruptcy and to move closer to monopoly power), and the broader increase in economic and political power of the biggest financial services players over the past 20 years and the last 6 months – this is potentially damaging to all consumers and, obviously, to all taxpayers.

If the DOJ and/or FTC want to investigate Bank of America for swallowing Merrill, Lynch, have at it. Anyone for a triple damages action that could sweep in the Fed and the Treasury? Be my guest if you can figure out how. The scary part of this, however, is the suggestion that antitrust should be deployed for broader purposes-containing “economic and political power.” That has a nostalgic ring to it, if you like old-fashioned antitrust.

The concern that antitrust enforcers might once again pull the pitchforks from the barn and go after firms for grounds unrelated to competition and efficiency is not far-fetched. My friend Bob Lande, who fits most anyone’s definition of antitrust zealot, nonetheless saw fit to gently (too gently) chide the majority in the FTC’s N-Data opinion for attacking conduct that was claimed to be “unjust, inequitable or . . . contrary to good morals.”  Stringent competition doesn’t mean being nice. Good morals? Are we going to enforce the Golden Rule for competitors? We wouldn’t want somebody cheating on a rival, would we?

It is to be expected that the new administration will move in the direction of more aggressive antitrust enforcement. I’ll be happy if the new policy emerges from a process that engages the arguments of the Section 2 Report. But given the current environment, I will not be surprised if we see competitive concerns share the stage with a wide range of other goals and motivations. The Section 2 Report envisions predictable, principled, and coherent enforcement. That’s a noble, if tough to achieve vision, but it is one that has little chance of materializing if antitrust embraces a whole set of conflicting concerns.

5 responses to Section 2 Symposium: Howard Marvel–An Economist’s View

  1. 

    A little off-topic, but since you’re building on Akerlof and Shiller’s theme of capitalism as a game…

    “Law 18, still unwritten but frequently quoted as the ultimate goal of refereeing: ‘Intelligence in
    the perception of the game, the attitude of the players, the place and the moment of the offense.'”

    http://www.ayso11l.org/Forms/Referee/AdvicetoRef07.pdf

  2. 

    There may be better arguments for it, but I’d also note that something like this seems to be happening in the importation of privacy concerns into (at least) merger analysis. As it happens, Josh and I are holding a conference later this week that will cover this topic in part (see the conference website at http://innovationforum.gmu.edu/). And although it’s easy to throw around the notion that privacy is a product characteristic in certain markets, and monopoly creates an incentive for certain firms to degrade privacy protections, I’ve really never seen a satisfactory effort to explain the mechanism–little more than the assertion that monopolist firms may skimp on privacy, so antitrust should consider privacy effects. But why? There may be good reasons for it, but before we jump head first into these uncharted and uncertain waters, shouldn’t we have a theory and some evidence to guide us?

  3. 
    Josh Wright 4 May 2009 at 7:58 pm

    Lest one get the impression that it only among the European competition enforcers and in the halls of MIT where this idea of “too big to fail” as an antitrust concept is gaining traction, an FTC Commissioner recently at least tentatively endorsed the proposition that “mergers should arguably be examined with an eye toward whether they are creating a merged entity that is “too big to fail.””

    I do wonder whether the growing support for the use of antitrust to achieve broader and sometimes conflicting social goals is at least partially a function of the contemporaneous rise in the view that error costs and concerns of false positives are overrated. If one views antitrust as a scalpel that enforcers have learned to master to fine tune the economy without significant fears of consumer welfare reducing errors, it might make sense to raise the degree of difficulty of the whole enterprise by tackling new political and social goals. Of course, neither economic theory, the existing empirical evidence or history support the scalpel view. But I think it is appropriate to highlight that these two forces might act together in ways that suggest dramatic change in the monopolization landscape in the years to come.

  4. 
    Alden Abbott 4 May 2009 at 2:19 pm

    It merits noting that the Secretary-General of the OECD (the “policy club” of the world’s wealthier economies)has called for governments to resist protectionism and maintain a vigorous competition policy, in light of the economic crisis conditions alluded to by Howard. See http://www.oecd.org/document/33/0,3343,en_40382599_40393105_41512929_1_1_1_1,00.html. The February 2009 OECD Global Forum on Competition discussed the importance of competition policy in a time of global economic crisis.

Trackbacks and Pingbacks:

  1. TRUTH ON THE MARKET » Coda: Varney withdraws Section 2 Report - September 17, 2009

    […] Section 2  Symposium, the news is jarring, although not unexpected.  Moreover, as predicted in Howard Marvel’s first post here, Varney is using “recent events” in the economy as a lever: Varney said that while […]