The Economist on the death of Howrey and future of Big Law

Larry Ribstein —  6 May 2011

The Economist covers the shrinkage of Big Law, focusing on Howrey’s demise. The article covers themes in my recent papers, particularly including Death of Big Law, Law’s Information Revolution and Practicing Theory.  It particularly points out what I discussed in Death of Big Law:

Howrey’s fall shows just how fragile even a 55-year-old firm can be. Since a firm’s only real assets are its partners, when a few departures turn into an exodus, the end can be shockingly quick.

What triggered Howrey’s implosion?  The Economist echoes my assessment that it reflects three big trends rather than just a “cyclical” phenomenon: “clients’ determination to keep their bills down;” outsourcing, and “the growth of technology in an industry long synonymous with trained human judgment.”

Howrey boss Robert Ruyak blamed clients’ resistance to hourly billing and e-discovery vendors.  But as I’ve discussed these are symptoms of deeper causes, including the big trends just listed.

The Economist suggests that the firms likely survive include elite wide-spectrum firms like Davis Polk & Wardwell; Sullivan & Cromwell; Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton; and Simpson Thacher & Bartlett; specialist firms  such as m & a specialists Wachtell and Cravath.

My prediction (from Death of Big Law at 777) is both more general and more precise:

The basic question confronting the large law firm is the extent to which these firms produce substantial profits at the firm level, or instead are just aggregations of lawyers or of relatively small networks of lawyers. The theory of the Big Law “firm” is based on the idea that the firm generates reputational capital. However, the conditions for maintaining this capital, particularly including seniority-based compensation and a rigid up-or-out promotion tournament, exist only in a relatively few top-line firms, such as Cravath. Many more have adopted the Big Law form without the internal structure necessary to maintain it.

This supports the Economist’s prediction for the success of “elite” firms, but bodes ill for what the Economist refers to as a third class of firms that are “big and well-known, but do not have the glittering reputations of the first two groups,” including Jones Day, DLA Piper and Baker & McKenzie.  As the article says, “[t]here is money in globalising, but not enough for everyone.”  The major factor in big firm survival is the firm’s ability to maintain the reputational bonds that hold firms together. Globalization makes this harder, not easier.  Moreover, the article points out that globalization thrusts firms into countries that “protect their turf” against foreign intruders.

In sum, the article notes, “lawyering is becoming more of a business than a profession. * * * Because the American market cannot grow as it used to, firms will have to find new strategies and make use of sophisticated branding to stand out.” This may require lawyers “becoming experts in other industries,” or joining with other professionals in “all-in-one professional-service firms.”  These are among the approaches my articles discuss.

But I note in my and Kobayashi’s Information Revolution and in Practicing Theory that the changes in the legal profession won’t stop with new types of law firms.  The end game is the creation of a new “legal information” industry.

Larry Ribstein

Posts

Professor of Law, University of Illinois College of Law

One response to The Economist on the death of Howrey and future of Big Law

  1. 

    One of the great inefficiencies of the legal field is the need for “stars” to do everything. Yes, there are certain lawyers who are true stars in their field and are worth the millions of dollars they generate. But how much legal work really requires a star and how much is just mundaine legal work that any qualified lawyer could do? I would say that the actual percentage of legal work that requires “star talent” is pretty small. Yet, big law has always gone out of its way to hire and pay only star talent. That seems to me to be a massive ineffeciency.

    Why not have a star talent as a money generating partner supported by a group of attorneys from middle tier schools earning half what the typical big firm associate makes? To give a sports analogy, it would be ineffecient to have an NBA team made up of 12 all stars each making the maximum salary. You need people who come off the bench and rebound and do things besides be the best player on the team. Also, in the day and age of instant, communication, I don’t understand why big law is so concentrated in a few high expense cities. The most profitable model would be to take two or three super star partners, move out to a smaller lower cost city and higher a group of competant and reasonably priced associates and paralegals to do the grunt work.